Πηγή: Γ. Βαρουφάκης
Mark Weisbrot has been arguing, for some time now, that Greece must try to emulate
Argentina; that is, to default on its debts not as a bargaining strategy that
yields a New Deal within the Eurozone but, rather, in the context of exiting
the Eurozone altogether and going it alone. Recently, Paul Krugman has endorsed
this position (see here and here). I think they are profoundly wrong.
There are two arguments against the
recommendation that Greece and Argentina are similar enough to warrant an
Argentinian road for Greece. There are those, like the Cato Institute and
IMF diehards, who never forgave Argentina for having successfully escaped the
clutches of the poisonous austerity (and internal devaluation) that the IMF had
imposed upon the country so as to sacrifice a whole people’s prosperity in the
interest of creditors, rentiers and assorted speculators who had flooded the
country with dollars (during the era of the currency board). Believe me when I
say that I am not one of them. Indeed, I salute the Argentinian people for
having toppled a regime, and more than one government, that tried so
desperately to sacrifice a proud people on the altar of IMF-led austerity. No,
my criticism of the idea that Greece can ‘do’ an Argentina today stems from the
view that the circumstances Greece is facing today are genuinely different to
those of Argentina a decade ago.
The differences between the two cases,
which render the analogy redundant, are three:
1st difference:
The potential of exports to act as shock absorbers
Weisbrot and Krugman point out, correctly,
that at the height of Argentina’s crisis, its exports (as a percentage of GDP)
were not very different to those of Greece. Based on this argument, they
dismiss the idea that Argentina managed to recover after its
default-devaluation by means of export-led growth.
While it is quite true that Argentina’s
export performance in 2001 was by no means better than Greece’s today, it is
crucial to note that Argentina’s export
potential in 2001 was vastly superior to that
of Greece’s in 2012. By export
potential I mean the degree of
underutilisation of productive resources whose employment can, potentially,
produce goods and services for which there is effective demand. In 2001,
Argentina’s farms were woefully underproducing primary commodities that were,
at that time, seeing their demand skyrocket. In sharp contrast, idle productive
resources in Greece cannot produce much for which there is increasing demand.
Take for instance shipping and tourism,
mentioned by Paul Krugman as two potential sources of Greek export growth: Both
are in speedy decline! Additionally, whereas in the case of Argentina, its next
door neighbour (Brazil) was entering a period of rapid growth, Greece’s
neighbours are showing no such signs of vitality. Indeed, our traditional
trading partners are also buffeted by recession (pushing down the demand for
Greek tourism) while non-EU countries (such as Russia) cannot, and will not,
make up the difference to any appreciable degree.
Lastly, on this note, Weisbrot and his co-author Juan Antonio Montesino argue
that Argentina’s growth was not ‘export’ driven, noting that only 12% of its
GDP growth during the 2002-8 period can be accounted for by exports. With all
due respect, I fear that such a pronouncement cannot be made lightly. For it is
impossible to separate neatly the effects on GDP of exports from the effect of
internal aggregate demand when we take into account the fact that internal
demand relies entirely on ‘animal spirits’ (i.e. on the optimistic
expectations) of investors into goods intended for local consumption. Put
simply, the emergence of strong Chinese demand for Argentinian soy, beef etc.,
in conjunction with the growth of neighbouring Brazil, has had a major impact
on the readiness of Argentinian investors to invest in activities that also
generated internal demand. In short, that 12% quoted by Weisbrot is simply a
gross underestimate.
2nd difference:
Greece has no peg with the euro. It has the euro!
Analysts like Krugman, Weisbrot and Rubini
make the utterly good point that Greece would benefit enormously from a
devaluation of its currency. Of course it would. Argentina does, indeed,
provide a brilliant example of how a massive devaluation can help a country
escape a debt-deflationary cycle. As, for that matter, does Iceland. However,
what they are neglecting is that it is one thing to break a peg linking your
currency to some other hard currency (as in the case of Argentina), or to
devalue your floating currency (as did Iceland), and quite another to have no
currency but to have to create one from scratch.
In the case of Argentina the peso was in
existence. All it took to devalue it was to announce that the 1:1 peg with the
dollar was over. Suddenly ALL incomes and ALL savings were devalued by the same
percentage. Overnight. End of story. It was not pleasant but it could be done.
In the case of Greece it simply cannot. And this makes a world of a difference.
Why? Because of two important reasons. First, because of the crushing delay in
introducing a new currency. Secondly, because of what I call the bifurcation
between the stock of savings and the flow of incomes. But let me take these one
at a time.
Delay: Bank of Greece colleagues tell me that it will
take months before ATMs are stocked with new drachmas once they get the go
ahead to print them. Even if it takes weeks, an economy cannot remain un-monetised
for so long, especially when already on the canvass of a deep crisis, without
major civil unrest and an almost terminal effect on economic activity.
Bifurcation: Even ignoring the crippling effects of the delay, we
must not forget that the ongoing crises has led Greek savers to withdraw oodles
of their savings from Greek banks and either shift them offshore (London,
Geneva, Frankfurt) or stuff them in their mattresses, or hide them in their
freezers (in ‘bricks’ of 500 notes). This means that, by the time
we come to an exit from the euro, the stock
of savings will be in euros and the flow of incomes and pensions (once the banks re-open) will be in drachmas.
So, unlike in Argentina, a Greek euro-exit will drive a wedge between stocks and flows, savings and incomes; with the former revaluing
massively relative to the latter. Moreover, the very availability of such large
quantities of ‘hard’ currency savings, in the hands of the average Dimitri and
Kiki on the street, will ensure that the decline in the value of the new
drachma will be precipitous (something that did not happen in Argentina since
most savings were in pesos also).
In short, even if we neglect the
devastation caused by the delay in the introduction of the new currency
(something Argentina did not have to worry about), the new currency will be
debased ever so quickly due to this bifurcation, leading to hyperinflation and
the loss of most of the competitive gains we might have hoped for from the
devaluation.
3rd difference:
Greece is perfectly capable of poisoning the water it is swimming in (Europe)
When Argentina defaulted and broke the
peg, the ill effects on its trading partners (China, Brazil etc.), as well as
on the broader macro-economy in which it was functioning, were negligible. If
Greece leaves the euro, however, the results will most certainly prove
catastrophic for our ‘economic ecology’, and in a never-ending circle of
negative feedback, will bite our struggling nation back.
To begin with, Greece must exit not only
the Eurozone but also the European Union. This is non-negotiable and
unavoidable. For if the Greek state is effectively to confiscate the few euros
a citizen has in her bank account and turn them into drachmas of diminishing
value, she will be able to take the Greek government to the European Courts and
win outright. Additionally, the Greek state will have to introduce border and
capital controls to prevent the export of its citizens euro-savings. Thus,
Greece will have to get out of the European Union.
Setting aside the domestic ramifications
over loss of agricultural subsidies, structural funds and possibly trade
(following the possible introduction of trade barriers between Greece and the
EU), the effects on the rest of the Eurozone will also be cataclysmic. Spain,
already in a black hole, will see its GDP shrink by more than Greece’s current
deflationary record rate, interest rate spreads will tend to 20% in Ireland and
in Italy and, before long, Germany will decide to call it a day, bailing itself
out (in unison with other surplus countries). This chain of events will cause a
bitter recession in the surplus countries clustered around Germany, whose
currency will appreciate through the roof, while the rest of Europe will sink
into the mire of stagflation.
How good will this environment be for
Greece? I submit it to you, dear reader, that the answer is: Not good at all!
In short, whereas Argentina’s and
Iceland’s successful default-devaluation strategy did not have adverse effects
on the overarching environment in which they had to exist after their bold
move, a Greek euro-exit will be the equivalent to poisoning the pool in which
we must swim.
Epilogue
Does this mean that Greece ought to grin and bear the massive and
misanthropic idiocy of the bailout-austerity package imposed upon it by the
troika (EU-ECB-IMF)? Of course not. We should certainly default. But within the
Eurozone. (See here for
this argument.) And use our readiness to default as a bargaining strategy by
which to bring about a New Deal for Europe (in a manner that I have written
about here). http://youpayyourcrisis.blogspot.com
I thought you might be interested in this. A company based in Canada called CashSender.com is offering the ordinary Greek savers a line-line.
ΑπάντησηΔιαγραφήhttp://www.robinbuxton.com/2012/05/greece-leaving-euro-emergency-plan-for.html